000 | 01936cam a2200229 i 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
020 | _a0198766866 | ||
020 | _a9780198766865 | ||
082 | 0 | 4 | _a320 |
100 | 1 | _aLindvall, Johannes, | |
245 | 1 | 0 | _aReform capacity / |
250 | _aFirst edition. | ||
300 |
_aviii, 161 pages : _billustrations ; |
||
505 | 2 | _aTwo theories of effective government -- Compensating the losers -- How reforms fail -- Formal and informal power -- Future-oriented reforms -- Reform capacity. | |
520 | 8 | _aIt is often said that effective government requires a concentration of power. If we want our political leaders to adjust public policies to changing economic, social, and political circumstances, we should, in this view, leave our leaders alone: we should put in place electoral procedures that identify a clear winner in each election, and then we should let the winning political party govern without having to cooperate with others. The argument of this book is that this view is mistaken, since it seriously underestimates the ability of political decision makers to overcome democratic paralysis by compensating losers (groups that stand to lose from a reform). Reform capacity - the ability of political decision makers to adopt and implement policy changes that benefit society as a whole - can therefore be achieved in both power-concentration systems (which enable governments to ignore losers) and power-sharing systems (where governments build support for reform by compensating losers). If political decision makers are able to solve the bargaining problems that sometimes complicate negotiations between winners and losers, power-sharing systems have certain advantages over power-concentration systems. | |
650 | 0 | _aPolitical planning. | |
650 | 0 | _aPublic administration | |
650 | 0 | _aCoalition governments. | |
650 | 7 | _aCoalition governments. | |
650 | 7 | _aPolitical planning. | |
650 | 7 | _aPublic administration | |
942 | _cBK | ||
999 |
_c3051 _d3051 |